The Mughal Empire

The Mughal Empire


Book Review

Author: John F. Richards

Year: 1995

Publisher: Cambridge University Press

As part of the new Cambridge history of India, Richards' work as a single-volume, coherent narrative history of the Mughal empire (covering the period from 1526 to 1720) focuses on how the collapse of the centralized formal apparatus of the Mughal empire impacted its decline in the later years.

Richards begins his history from Bābar's victory at Panipat in 1526 and ends it with the period around Muhammad Shāh's accession in Delhi in 1720. According to Richards, the basic structure of this centralized empire had badly disintegrated in the bitter war of succession between 1707 and 1720. The administrative structure of skilled technical staff lost its efficiency and effectiveness. In these circumstances, two central institutions – the revenue zabt (system) and the assignment of jāgirs[1] – were badly affected as a consequence with jāgirs rapidly becoming local fiefs. However, Richards presents a different view from that of Irfan Habib in response to the question whether this rapid collapse could have been the result of a "jāgir crisis" in the widening gap between the financial demands of the mansabdārs[2]and revenue-yielding lands to meet those needs. Habib argues that, since the jāgīrdār[3] did not hold his land for more than three or four years before transfer, he did not maintain any long-term interest in the peasantry. Hence, a jāgīrdār's short-term needs inclined him to "sanction any act of oppression that conferred an immediate benefit upon him, even if it ruined the peasantry and so destroyed the revenue-paying capacity of that area for all time."[4] The zamīndārs[5] squeezed between the peasantry and the jāgirdārs entered into armed revolt and rebellions (as those of the Jāts and the Sikhs, and, then as those in the form of the Mahratta resistance in the Deccan). Richards, on the other hand, shows that checks against abuse built into the system as early as during Akbar's time continued up to Awrangzēb's period (who, for example, retained many productive tracts in Golconda and Bijapur under his own control). Richards also refers to other critics who have pointed out difficulties in identifying the links in the oppression of jāgirdārs, agrarian resistance, and imperial decline. He agrees with other critics that transfers of jāgīrs for large holders may not have been as frequent as previously thought and many nobles may have held on to the lands for 10 years or more.[6] In Richards' opinion therefore the jāgīr crisis, while certainly serious, was not the central reason for imperial decline. In fact, the shortage of productive jāgīr lands, according to Richards, can be traced to official policy and the devastation and dislocation wrought by the Deccan wars. Richards believes that, in the wake of these wars, the system of non-hereditary salary assignments and the regulation of land tax system weakened. In part, the reasons for the revolts in northern India could also be traced to the inattentive administration in the years that Awrangzēb was involved in the Deccan.

Richards has emphasized centralized Mughal authority, particularly as it was instituted during Akbar's time and projected in the persona of an ideal king in Abū al-Fadl's Akbar Nāmah and Ā'īn-i Akbarī as the foundation of the empire. Two linkages were essential for this centralized authority: the ties of emotion and interest that bound the nobility to the throne and the contractual ties of self-interest that linked the rural aristocracies to the empire. The administrative structure and its ethos aimed at converting both linkages into dependable imperial servants. Both linkages came under great strain between 1689 and 1720. Shrinking frontiers, confusion, and loss of confidence halted the process that had steadily transformed each of the two groups into foundations for sustaining the centralized Mughal authority.

Awrangzēb failed to repair his relationship with the Rajputs or to incorporate the Mahrattas or the Telugus as participants in the governance of the empire. As a consequence of Akbar's reforms, most zamīndārs and peasants were prospering in about 1580s to 1700. Richards argues that the very success of the Mughal agrarian system brought about important changes in rural society. These changes required but did not receive attention and adjustment by the later regime. War, Richards points out, was after all the principal enterprise of the Mughal emperors, who allocated a great deal of their resources to the military, and the later Timurid regime did not succeed in converting armed zamīndars into less-powerful but useful, quasi-officials who would reliably carry out imperial policy.

Since Richards' thesis revolves around the strength of the centralized administrative authority in a devolutionary set up and the strength of the military machinery, he devotes a substantive portion of his book to the description of Akbar's personality, policies, and approach.[7] The reader cannot also but notice contrasts later in an equally substantive portion devoted to a description of the same elements in Awrangzēb.[8] Richards gives many details to explain how Akbar organized a complex administrative set-up and land-revenue system in which the ranking system of the mansabdārs ensured meritocracy and what Alvi terms as a professional 'asabiyyah that transcended ethnic or religious bounds on the one hand and sustained and augmented an ethos of loyalty and fidelity to the king.[9] Abū al-Fadl's portrayal of the Perfect Pādeshāh,[10] even as super-hyperbolic amalgam of Persian illuminationist, Islamic khilāfat,[11] Sufi pīr (master), Prophetic Mahdī,[12] and shar'ī mujtahid-imām[13] themes, is reflective of the expectancies of utmost devotion to the Mughal sovereign where the ultimate service is in the form of complete discipleship. Although, true to his spirit of tolerance in religion, Akbar did not force his nobility as such to accept his Dīn-i Illāhī,[14] yet it reflected the kind of devotion and loyalty that was expected in a system where the decision of placement within Akbar's ranking system finally depended on the emperor's favour. Akbar's disenchantment with strict interpretations of religion had begun early and many of his measures (as abolition of heavy taxation from Hindu pilgrims in 1563, permission of apostasy to forcibly converted non-Muslims, and the end of jizyah in 1579) would strongly impact the sensibilities of the subjects he ruled.[15] Furthermore, his administrative genius also lay in not allowing any group, including the 'ulamā, to be too powerful in its own right. Yet, it was not just force, organization, or military brilliance, but also a profound mix of political compromises (including marriage into the Rajputs and accepting them into nobility) and realpolitik that marked his enormous success. In contrast, even though Awrangzēb had many more Hindu mansabdārs in his court, there are striking differences in his approach towards the 'ulamā,[16] the sharī'ah,[17] arts, jizyah, and his own persona (where the concept of khānahzād[18] gains preponderance over discipleship as epitomizing devotion to the emperor), et cetera. A deeper analysis of these factors is certainly required, which this book does not offer in contrast with the in-depth analysis of the aftermath of the Deccan campaigns and the changes in the administrative and military effectiveness.

The author's allusions to many other aspects of Mughal rule successfully generate interest – as he intended – but, since he does not delve into these aspects as such, they leave room for further study to look into many questions of import. Inter alia, these questions include: a further study of succession wars,[19] the role of religion and religious ideas and developments,[20] and, in comparison with Europe, the slow development of military apparatus and technology.[21]

Although the book serves its basic purpose of providing a coherent, narrative history that reads like a novel, generates great interest, and presents an important thesis cogently, yet, with focus on critique of the Marxist Aligarh school, there is not sufficient referencing for a more serious reader or a fruitful explanation of the sources and the historiographical approaches used in presenting other ideas of import.[22] For example, in referring to ideological developments, the original, religious sources do not usually find any mention or analysis.[23] Although formal transliteration has not been used, yet more attention could have been given to spelling and consistency.[24]

Despite some of these lacunae, the book serves as a useful primer that needs to be supplemented with other readings to look into the many interesting questions it raises about the Mughal history in India – a history that has become increasingly pertinent to the understanding of intellectual, social and political traditions of contemporary Indian-subcontinent.[25]




Articles by this author


Discourse on Knowledge and Beliefs

Abdus Sattar Ghauri (You will be missed!)

Discourse on Knowledge and Beliefs

Discourse on Knowledge and Beliefs

Review of Walid A. Saleh’s Article on Al-Wāhidīs

Lesbianism and Islam

Your Questions Answered

A Note on Ijmā‘

The Mughal Empire

Letter to the Christian Community on the Recent Gojra Tragedy

CII, Divorce Laws, and Argumentum ad Baculum

Twinkle, Twinkle

Trivializing Homosexuality

Wither, Wither

“Ask Naught of Me but the Tale of Promise and Loyalty”

A Discussion on Sufism, Epistemology, and Usul

Wanderings

In Hope and in Fear

The Taj

In Hope and in Fear

Take Not the Joy Away!

Email from Canada: Lamentations of a Sinner

Rent and Riba

The Meaning of Riba

Recommendations for Improving Education in Pakistan

The Redundant Warriors

Repeated Grave Sins

Your Questions Answered

Your Questions Answered

A Man’s First Foes

A Man’s First Foes

The Status of the Stock Exchange

Your Questions Answered

What if He is?

CA-15 and Love Laws

Blasphemy (A Novel)

Qital Without the Authority of the State

Smiling Alone*

Professionalism in Teaching

Tawhid in Sufism

Rent and Riba

The Meaning of Riba

Until Daylight….

Murder, Manslaughter and Terrorism—All in the Name of Allah

Quis Custodiet Ipsos Custodes?

Thou Mayst Kill!

Wali’s Consent In Marriage

Money is Everything!

Smiling Alone

No Jihad Without the State

O Si Sic Omnia!1

To Devalue or Not to Devalue?—That’s Not the Question

Tawhid in Sufism

Bank Job

The Budget 1996-97 For Whom the Bell Tolls? (Part 2/2)

The Budget 1996-97 For Whom the Bell Tolls? (Part 1/2)

Shaikh Mahmud Ahmad’s Concept of Time Multiple Counter Loan

Quid Rides?*

The Art of Interpretation

Did God need Creation?

The Meaning of Riba

Preformance of the Economy

Halalah

No Jihad Without the State

Editorial

Why Religion?

Whither Justice?

Order Of The Quranic Groups

Why Religion?

Raffle-Tickets

The Status of the Stock Exchange

Halaal Meat

Prohibition of Pig-Meat And Liquor

The Existence Of God

MUS`AB PUBLIC SCHOOL: An Introduction

The Authenticity Of Hadith

SHEIKH MAHMOOD AHMAD’S CONCEPT OF TIME MULTIPLE COUNTER LOAN

Rent and Ribaa

Exploitative Interest

`I Am Allah, You Are Allah,  Every One Is Allah!’

No `Ology’ Like Etymology!

Tazkia-i-Nafs

‘....but some animals are more equal than others’